Maximal Lotteries
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Maximal lotteries refers to a probabilistic
voting system An electoral system or voting system is a set of rules that determine how elections and referendums are conducted and how their results are determined. Electoral systems are used in politics to elect governments, while non-political elections ma ...
first considered by the French mathematician and social scientist Germain KrewerasG. Kreweras. ''Aggregation of preference orderings''. In Mathematics and Social Sciences I: Proceedings of the seminars of Menthon-Saint-Bernard, France (1–27 July 1960) and of Gösing, Austria (3–27 July 1962), pages 73–79, 1965. in 1965. The method uses preferential ballots and returns so-called maximal lotteries, i.e., probability distributions over the alternatives that are weakly preferred to any other probability distribution. Maximal lotteries satisfy the
Condorcet criterion An electoral system satisfies the Condorcet winner criterion () if it always chooses the Condorcet winner when one exists. The candidate who wins a majority of the vote in every head-to-head election against each of the other candidatesthat is, a ...
, the
Smith criterion The Smith criterion (sometimes generalized Condorcet criterion, but this can have other meanings) is a voting systems criterion defined such that it's satisfied when a voting system always elects a candidate that is in the Smith set, which is the ...
,
reversal symmetry Reversal symmetry is a voting system criterion which requires that if candidate A is the unique winner, and each voter's individual preferences are inverted, then A must not be elected. Methods that satisfy reversal symmetry include Borda count, r ...
, polynomial runtime, and probabilistic versions of
reinforcement In behavioral psychology, reinforcement is a consequence applied that will strengthen an organism's future behavior whenever that behavior is preceded by a specific antecedent stimulus. This strengthening effect may be measured as a higher freq ...
,F. Brandl, F. Brandt, and H. G. Seedig
Consistent probabilistic social choice
Econometrica. 84(5), pages 1839-1880, 2016.
participation Participation or Participant may refer to: Politics *Participation (decision making), mechanisms for people to participate in social decisions *Civic participation, engagement by the citizens in government *e-participation, citizen participation ...
,F. Brandl, F. Brandt, and J. Hofbauer
Welfare Maximization Entices Participation
Games and Economic Behavior. 14, pages 308-314, 2019.
and
independence of clones In voting systems theory, the independence of clones criterion measures an election method's robustness to strategic nomination. Nicolaus Tideman was the first to formulate this criterion, which states that the winner must not change due to the ...
. Maximal lotteries are equivalent to mixed maximin strategies (or
Nash equilibria In game theory, the Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematician John Nash, is the most common way to define the solution of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In a Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equili ...
) of the symmetric
zero-sum game Zero-sum game is a mathematical representation in game theory and economic theory of a situation which involves two sides, where the result is an advantage for one side and an equivalent loss for the other. In other words, player one's gain is e ...
given by the pairwise majority margins. As such, they have a natural interpretation in terms of electoral competition between two political parties. Laslier, J.-F. ''Interpretation of electoral mixed strategies'' Social Choice and Welfare 17: pages 283–292, 2000. Moreover, they can be computed using
linear programming Linear programming (LP), also called linear optimization, is a method to achieve the best outcome (such as maximum profit or lowest cost) in a mathematical model whose requirements are represented by linear function#As a polynomial function, li ...
. The voting system that returns all maximal lotteries is axiomatically characterized as the only one satisfying probabilistic versions of population-consistency (a weakening of reinforcement) and composition-consistency (a strengthening of independence of clones). A
social welfare function In welfare economics, a social welfare function is a function that ranks social states (alternative complete descriptions of the society) as less desirable, more desirable, or indifferent for every possible pair of social states. Inputs of the f ...
that top-ranks maximal lotteries is characterized using Arrow's
independence of irrelevant alternatives The independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA), also known as binary independence or the independence axiom, is an axiom of decision theory and various social sciences. The term is used in different connotation in several contexts. Although it a ...
and
Pareto efficiency Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian civil engine ...
.F. Brandl and F. Brandt
Arrovian Aggregation of Convex Preferences
Econometrica. 88(2), pages 799-844, 2020.
Maximal lotteries satisfy a strong notion of
Pareto efficiency Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian civil engine ...
and a weak notion of
strategyproof In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information about ...
ness.H. Aziz, F. Brandt, and M Brill
On the Tradeoff between Economic Efficiency and Strategyproofness
Games and Economic Behavior. 110, pages 1-18, 2018.
In contrast to random dictatorship, maximal lotteries do not satisfy the standard notion of strategyproofness. Also, maximal lotteries are not
monotonic In mathematics, a monotonic function (or monotone function) is a function between ordered sets that preserves or reverses the given order. This concept first arose in calculus, and was later generalized to the more abstract setting of order ...
in probabilities, i.e., it is possible that the probability of an alternative decreases when this alternative is ranked up. However, the probability of the alternative will remain positive. Laslier, J.-F. ''Tournament solutions and majority voting'' Springer-Verlag, 1997. Maximal lotteries or variants thereof have been rediscovered multiple times by economists,G. Laffond, J.-F. Laslier, and M. Le Breton. ''The bipartisan set of a tournament game''. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(1):182–201, 1993. mathematicians,P. C. Fishburn. ''Probabilistic social choice based on simple voting comparisons''. Review of Economic Studies, 51(4):683–692, 1984.D. C. Fisher and J. Ryan. ''Tournament games and positive tournaments''. Journal of Graph Theory, 19(2):217–236, 1995. political scientists, philosophers,D. S. Felsenthal and M. Machover. ''After two centuries should Condorcet’s voting procedure be implemented?'' Behavioral Science, 37(4):250–274, 1992. and computer scientists. R. L. Rivest and E. Shen. An optimal single-winner preferential voting system based on game theory. In Proceedings of 3rd International Workshop on Computational Social Choice, pages 399–410, 2010. In particular, the support of maximal lotteries, which is known as the ''essential set''B. Dutta and J.-F. Laslier. ''Comparison functions and choice correspondences''. Social Choice and Welfare, 16: 513–532, 1999. or the ', has been studied in detail.F. Brandt, M. Brill, H. G. Seedig, and W. Suksompong. ''On the structure of stable tournament solutions''. Economic Theory, 65(2):483–507, 2018. Similar ideas appear also in the study of reinforcement learning and evolutionary biology to explain the multiplicity of co-existing species.B. Laslier and J.-F. Laslier. ''Reinforcement learning from comparisons: Three alternatives are enough, two are not'' Annals of Applied Probability 27(5): 2907–2925, 2017.Jacopo Grilli, György Barabás, Matthew J. Michalska-Smith and Stefano Allesina. ''Higher-order interactions stabilize dynamics in competitive network models'' Nature 548: 210-214, 2017.


Collective preferences over lotteries

The input to this voting system consists of the agents' ordinal preferences over outcomes (not lotteries over alternatives), but a relation on the set of lotteries can be constructed in the following way: if p and q are lotteries over alternatives, p\succ q if the expected value of the margin of victory of an outcome selected with distribution p in a head-to-head vote against an outcome selected with distribution q is positive. In other words, p\succ q if it is more likely that a randomly selected voter will prefer the alternatives sampled from p to the alternative sampled from q than vice versa. While this relation is not necessarily transitive, it does always contain at least one maximal element. It is possible that several such maximal lotteries exist, but unicity can be proven in the case where the margins between any pair of alternatives is always an odd number. This is the case for instance if there is an odd number of voters who all hold strict preferences over the alternatives. Following the same argument, unicity holds for the original "bipartisan set" that is defined as the support of the maximal lottery of a tournament game.


Example

Suppose there are five voters who have the following preferences over three alternatives: * 2 voters: a\succ b\succ c * 2 voters: b\succ c\succ a * 1 voter: c\succ a\succ b The pairwise preferences of the voters can be represented in the following
skew-symmetric matrix In mathematics, particularly in linear algebra, a skew-symmetric (or antisymmetric or antimetric) matrix is a square matrix whose transpose equals its negative. That is, it satisfies the condition In terms of the entries of the matrix, if a_ ...
, where the entry for row x and column y denotes the number of voters who prefer x to y minus the number of voters who prefer y to x. \begin \begin & & a\quad & b\quad & c\quad \\ \end \\ \begin a\\ b\\ c\\ \end \begin 0 & 1 & -1\\ -1 & 0 & 3\\ 1 & -3 & 0\\ \end \end This matrix can be interpreted as a
zero-sum game Zero-sum game is a mathematical representation in game theory and economic theory of a situation which involves two sides, where the result is an advantage for one side and an equivalent loss for the other. In other words, player one's gain is e ...
and admits a unique
Nash equilibrium In game theory, the Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematician John Nash, is the most common way to define the solution of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In a Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equili ...
(or minimax strategy) p where p(a)=3/5, p(b)=1/5, p(c)=1/5. By definition, this is also the unique maximal lottery of the preference profile above. The example was carefully chosen not to have a
Condorcet winner An electoral system satisfies the Condorcet winner criterion () if it always chooses the Condorcet winner when one exists. The candidate who wins a majority of the vote in every head-to-head election against each of the other candidatesthat is, a ...
. Many preference profiles admit a Condorcet winner, in which case the unique maximal lottery will assign probability 1 to the Condorcet winner.


References

{{Reflist


External links


voting.ml
(website for computing maximal lotteries)
Pnyx - Practical Preference Aggregation
(voting tool that, among other methods, offers maximal lotteries) Preferential electoral systems